Skip to main content

HS2 and cost-benefit analysis

The UK government has recently announced the route for the second leg of the long awaited high speed rail link between London and the north of England. This prompted the usual appeals to cost-benefit analysis to argue one way or the other. Most ‘experts’ seemed to be arguing that the supposed benefits are largely illusory and so the link does not make economic sense. But what does that really mean?
   Cost-benefit analysis is one of the most basic tools in the economist’s armoury. It’s pretty clear, however, that the general public don’t like it. Many people I heard on the radio talking about the rail link were annoyed by the experts cost-benefit calculations. Similarly, when health economists argue that a particular cancer drug should not be made available on the National Health Service because the costs exceed the benefits, people aren’t too pleased. So, what’s wrong with cost-benefit analysis?
    Given that I’m an economist it will be no surprise to hear that I don’t think anything is wrong with cost-benefit analysis. It’s one of the most basic principles of economics for a good reason –something is worth doing if and only the benefit exceeds the cost. What I have much less sympathy for is the way economists often use cost-benefit analysis.
   Doing a proper cost-benefit analysis is difficult because measuring potential benefits and costs can be a very tricky thing indeed. I’m excited by a high speed rail link because I want to see technological progress and development; how can you measure this benefit? Similarly, a cancer drug might add two years to a person’s life; how can you measure the benefit of that? I know there are ways we can attempt to measure these things, such as, willingness to pay and quality adjusted life years, but I also know how imperfect these measures are!
   So, my two concerns with the way economists often do cost-benefit analysis are as follows: (i) They make life easy for themselves by counting the simple to measure financial costs and benefits while ignoring the more difficult to measure costs and benefits; this often biases against the benefits. (ii) They underplay the huge margin for error in the calculation of costs and benefits; this leads to a sense of decisiveness that is not justified.
   It’s important, therefore, to appreciate the limitations of cost-benefit analysis. It is a useful tool but it cannot be expected to give clear cut answers. On tricky issues it is best used as a tool to inform and open debate rather than as a means to decide. Decisions should come down to questions of individual or democratic judgement. I, for one, would vote for the high speed rail link. Maybe you disagree. Just don't think cost-benefit analysis holds all the answers.   

Comments

Popular posts from this blog

Revealed preference, WARP, SARP and GARP

The basic idea behind revealed preference is incredibly simple: we try to infer something useful about a person's preferences by observing the choices they make. The topic, however, confuses many a student and academic alike, particularly when we get on to WARP, SARP and GARP. So, let us see if we can make some sense of it all.           In trying to explain revealed preference I want to draw on a  study  by James Andreoni and John Miller published in Econometrica . They look at people's willingness to share money with another person. Specifically subjects were given questions like:  Q1. Divide 60 tokens: Hold _____ at $1 each and Pass _____ at $1 each.  In this case there were 60 tokens to split and each token was worth $1. So, for example, if they held 40 tokens and passed 20 then they would get $40 and the other person $20. Consider another question: Q2. D...

Measuring risk aversion the Holt and Laury way

Attitudes to risk are a key ingredient in most economic decision making. It is vital, therefore, that we have some understanding of the distribution of risk preferences in the population. And ideally we need a simple way of eliciting risk preferences that can be used in the lab or field. Charles Holt and Susan Laury set out one way of doing in this in their 2002 paper ' Risk aversion and incentive effects '. While plenty of other ways of measuring risk aversion have been devised over the years I think it is safe to say that the Holt and Laury approach is the most commonly used (as the near 4000 citations to their paper testifies).           The basic approach taken by Holt and Laury is to offer an individual 10 choices like those in the table below. For each of the 10 choices the individual has to go for option A or option B. Most people go for option A in choice 1. And everyone should go for option B in choice 10. At some point, therefore, we expect the...

Nash bargaining solution

Following the tragic death of John Nash in May I thought it would be good to explain some of his main contributions to game theory. Where better to start than the Nash bargaining solution. This is surely one of the most beautiful results in game theory and was completely unprecedented. All the more remarkable that Nash came up with the idea at the start of his graduate studies!          The Nash solution is a 'solution' to a two-person bargaining problem . To illustrate, suppose we have Adam and Beth bargaining over how to split some surplus. If they fail to reach agreement they get payoffs €a and €b respectively. The pair (a, b) is called the disagreement point . If they agree then they can achieve any pair of payoffs within some set F of feasible payoff points . I'll give some examples later. For the problem to be interesting we need there to be some point (A, B) in F such that A > a and B > b. In...