Skip to main content

Culture and dishonesty in banking

The film 'A Good Year' starts with a ruthless financial trader called Max, played by Russell Crowe, manipulating bond markets in order to out-maneuver his competitors and make a quick, big profit. But, by the end of the film Max has decided to pack it all in and live out a more fulfilling life in rural France. Could that happen? Can someone really transition from a ruthless, selfish trader to a compassionate, loving family man in the space of a few days?
        A study by Alain Cohn, Ernst Fehr and Michel Marechal, publisehd in 2014 in Nature, suggests it might be possible. They used a standard coin tossing task to measure the dishonesty of 128 employees from a large, international bank. The task works as follows: A subject is asked to toss a coin 10 times and record whether the outcome was heads or tails. Depending on the outcome the subject can win $20 per toss. The crucial thing to know is that the subject records whether or not they won for each toss and there is no way for the experimenter to verify if the outcome is recorded correctly. So, the subject fills in the following table privately. This means a subject could 'easily' lie and walk away with $200.


        The crucial twist in the experiment was to vary the priming subjects faced before performing the coin-tossing task. Roughly half of the subjects were asked questions related to their work in the bank - Why did you decide to become a bank employee? What are the three major advantages of your occupation as a bank employee? Which three characteristics of your personality do you think are typical for a bank employee? etc. The other half of the subjects were asked questions not related to their work - What is your favorite leisure activity? Where did you spend your last vacation? Which three things did you like most about your last vacation? etc. 
        So, to the results. The figure below shows what happens for subjects not primed to think about work in the bank. The blue bars show the observed distribution of earnings and the green bars show the distribution of earnings expected by pure chance. We can see some hints of dishonesty - there are fewer than we would expect getting $40 or less and more getting $200. But, these are small things. The overall picture is that the bankers were honest.   


         Things change when subjects were primed to think about work in the bank. The distributions are shown below. Here we see a sizable increase in the amount of money being claimed. Needless to say, this is highly unlikely to be due to chance. It can be estimated that around 26% of subjects were dishonesty. Let us keep in perspective that this means 74% were honest. Even so, the headline result is that bankers only exhibit dishonesty when they are primed to think about banking.


        This finding feeds into a general debate about whether dishonesty is a personal trait or a product of culture. The results we have looked at here suggest that dishonesty has a large cultural component. That would make it more likely a banker can be ruthless in his job and then help old ladies across the road in his spare time. It is hard to imagine, however, that culture is the only factor at work here because we do know that there are reliable personal differences in dishonesty and willingness to cooperate. It is surely not by chance that some become investment bankers and others pediatricians? An interesting and closely related debate is whether studying economics makes people more selfish (culture at play) or whether more selfish people choose to study economics (personal traits at play). An article by Adam Grant provides a nice overview of the issues.  

Comments

Popular posts from this blog

Revealed preference, WARP, SARP and GARP

The basic idea behind revealed preference is incredibly simple: we try to infer something useful about a person's preferences by observing the choices they make. The topic, however, confuses many a student and academic alike, particularly when we get on to WARP, SARP and GARP. So, let us see if we can make some sense of it all.           In trying to explain revealed preference I want to draw on a  study  by James Andreoni and John Miller published in Econometrica . They look at people's willingness to share money with another person. Specifically subjects were given questions like:  Q1. Divide 60 tokens: Hold _____ at $1 each and Pass _____ at $1 each.  In this case there were 60 tokens to split and each token was worth $1. So, for example, if they held 40 tokens and passed 20 then they would get $40 and the other person $20. Consider another question: Q2. D...

Measuring risk aversion the Holt and Laury way

Attitudes to risk are a key ingredient in most economic decision making. It is vital, therefore, that we have some understanding of the distribution of risk preferences in the population. And ideally we need a simple way of eliciting risk preferences that can be used in the lab or field. Charles Holt and Susan Laury set out one way of doing in this in their 2002 paper ' Risk aversion and incentive effects '. While plenty of other ways of measuring risk aversion have been devised over the years I think it is safe to say that the Holt and Laury approach is the most commonly used (as the near 4000 citations to their paper testifies).           The basic approach taken by Holt and Laury is to offer an individual 10 choices like those in the table below. For each of the 10 choices the individual has to go for option A or option B. Most people go for option A in choice 1. And everyone should go for option B in choice 10. At some point, therefore, we expect the...

Nash bargaining solution

Following the tragic death of John Nash in May I thought it would be good to explain some of his main contributions to game theory. Where better to start than the Nash bargaining solution. This is surely one of the most beautiful results in game theory and was completely unprecedented. All the more remarkable that Nash came up with the idea at the start of his graduate studies!          The Nash solution is a 'solution' to a two-person bargaining problem . To illustrate, suppose we have Adam and Beth bargaining over how to split some surplus. If they fail to reach agreement they get payoffs €a and €b respectively. The pair (a, b) is called the disagreement point . If they agree then they can achieve any pair of payoffs within some set F of feasible payoff points . I'll give some examples later. For the problem to be interesting we need there to be some point (A, B) in F such that A > a and B > b. In...