Ask any self-respecting economics graduate the definition of
a public good and they will tell you the answer: it is a good that is
non-excludable and non-rivalrous. Which means that once it is provided
everybody gets to consume it, and that one person’s consumption of the good does
not detract from another person’s enjoyment of it. Simple enough, one might
think. But, I sense a lot of disagreement about the nature of public goods. For
example, I presented a paper recently on step-level public goods, and the
audience was keen to dispute that a step-level public good ‘really is’ a public
good. So, what’s the problem?
The definition of a public good only tells us about the
consumption side. It leaves a complete blank as to how the public good will be
produced. And this is where the differences start to surface. To most
economists, if you say public good, the picture that first comes to mind is of a
smooth linear or concave production function; the more people contribute
towards the public good the more is produced. To most psychologists, if you say
public good, the picture that comes to mind is seemingly of a step level
production function; contributions need to reach particular thresholds to
provide the good. We need not stop with these two examples. One can have a
minimum-effort production function in which the quantity of the public good is
determined by the minimum contribution. Or, one could have a best-shot
production function in which quantity is determined by the largest
contribution.
How a good is produced is irrelevant in determining whether
or not it is a public good. So, if people have a picture of what the production
function of a public good ‘should be like’ we get a source of confusion and disagreement.
The problem, however, is a little bit deeper than this. If the production
function is smooth then the public good is underprovided by the market. If the
production function is of the step-level, minimum effort or best-shot type then
the public good can be efficiently provided by the market. Economists are educated that public goods are
underprovided by the market; hence it is natural for them to associate public
goods with smooth production functions. Psychologists focus more on the
coordination aspect of providing public goods; hence it is natural for them to
associate public goods with step-level production functions. The confusion and disagreement
is not, therefore, just about production functions, its also about whether
markets can provide public goods efficiently.
This is worth keeping in mind when looking at public goods.
Economists, for instance, are almost certainly biased towards thinking
public goods cannot be provided by the market. Many public goods are, however,
provided by the market. It is crucial, therefore, to also think about how
public goods are produced.
Comments
Post a Comment