Skip to main content

Time to 'privatize' the NHS?

Labour's pitch for the upcoming UK general election has been simple - let's talk about the National Health Service. Particularly headline grabbing was the '100 days until the election, 100 days to save the NHS as we know it' campaign. To focus on the NHS may seem like a simple winning strategy for Labour given the rollercoaster of 'NHS in crisis' stories hitting the news in recent months. But, I think labour strategists may have badly misjudged this one. After years of dodging the issue the British public may finally waking up to the idea that we can only preserve the 'NHS as we know it' with some pretty radical change.
       The NHS is a publicly provided health care system that is centrally funded and free at the point of delivery. Labour is broadly committed to maintaining that status quo. They reject private involvement in providing health care. And they reject anything other than a free health service. 'Save our NHS, privatization is putting our NHS at grave risk' sums up the position nicely. The truth is, though, the NHS has to change. There simply is not enough money to fund the standard of service that Britons have got used to. So, we either accept a low standard of care or move to something different.
       The main problem with the NHS model is one of moral hazard: If the government guarantee a free health service then there is less incentive to stay healthy. And if people take more health risks then health costs will be higher than they need to be. Simple though it is this chain of logic needs some justification. After all, no one wants to be ill and so there are some big incentives to stay healthy! The 'free at the point of delivery' mantra has, however, created a society that expects great things from its NHS. That means this is not just a money issue; expectations of the NHS have grown well beyond what it can reasonably deliver. This also feeds into another consequence of moral hazard: people expect service immediately even for relatively minor problems.
       Charging for health care has already begun with a largely privatized dentistry, charges for prescriptions, and a growing private sector for routine operations. This trend will surely have to continue. What's interesting though are attitudes towards paying for health care. The 'free at the point of delivery' mantra is deeply ingrained in the British psyche; anyone who dared question its merits faced criticism. That's why labour might think it is on safe ground defending the NHS as we know it. Things though appear to be changing.
         I think this change partly reflects a growing understanding of individual choice in health care: people choose to get drunk on a Friday night, they choose to smoke, they choose to not eat healthy foods or exercise. Why should the taxpayer pay for health care that was avoidable? Surely the individual should take some of the responsibility? Another thing changing attitudes is the growing recognition that something has to give. The previous labour government put a lot of money into the NHS but that merely delayed the inevitable. People want a high quality health service and the current system is creaking at the edges. Can we not do better?
        Various ideas have been proposed to put additional charges into the NHS. Maybe it will be a nominal fee to visit a GP or A&E. Maybe benefits will be withdrawn from those who refuse to abide advice on healthy eating. Maybe it will be increasing private options in the NHS. One thing, however, seems clear and is often overlooked. Once charges are unleashed there is likely to be a run away train of increased charges. This is what happened with dentistry and is the kind of thing that will scare plenty of people. So, there needs to be a proper debate on what a future health service will look like. That is clearly not going to happen in this election with the conservatives afraid to mention the issue. Time is running out to really save the NHS as we know it.               

Comments

Popular posts from this blog

Revealed preference, WARP, SARP and GARP

The basic idea behind revealed preference is incredibly simple: we try to infer something useful about a person's preferences by observing the choices they make. The topic, however, confuses many a student and academic alike, particularly when we get on to WARP, SARP and GARP. So, let us see if we can make some sense of it all.           In trying to explain revealed preference I want to draw on a  study  by James Andreoni and John Miller published in Econometrica . They look at people's willingness to share money with another person. Specifically subjects were given questions like:  Q1. Divide 60 tokens: Hold _____ at $1 each and Pass _____ at $1 each.  In this case there were 60 tokens to split and each token was worth $1. So, for example, if they held 40 tokens and passed 20 then they would get $40 and the other person $20. Consider another question: Q2. Divide 40 tokens: Hold _____ at $1 each and Pass ______ at $3 each. In this case each token given to th

Nash bargaining solution

Following the tragic death of John Nash in May I thought it would be good to explain some of his main contributions to game theory. Where better to start than the Nash bargaining solution. This is surely one of the most beautiful results in game theory and was completely unprecedented. All the more remarkable that Nash came up with the idea at the start of his graduate studies!          The Nash solution is a 'solution' to a two-person bargaining problem . To illustrate, suppose we have Adam and Beth bargaining over how to split some surplus. If they fail to reach agreement they get payoffs €a and €b respectively. The pair (a, b) is called the disagreement point . If they agree then they can achieve any pair of payoffs within some set F of feasible payoff points . I'll give some examples later. For the problem to be interesting we need there to be some point (A, B) in F such that A > a and B > b. In other words Adam and Beth should be able to gain from agreeing.

Some estimates of price elasticity of demand

In the  textbook on Microeconomics and Behaviour with Bob Frank we have some tables giving examples of price, income and cross-price elasticities of demand. Given that most of the references are from the 70's I'm working on an update for the forthcoming 3rd edition. So, here is a brief overview of where the numbers come from for the table on price elasticity of demand. Suggestions for other good sources much appreciated. Before we get into the numbers - the disclaimer. Price elasticities are tricky things to tie down. Suppose you want the price elasticity of demand for cars. This elasticity is likely to be different for rich or poor people, people living in the city or the countryside, people in France or Germany etc.etc. You then have to think if you want the elasticity for buying a car or using a car (which includes petrol, insurance and so on). So, there is no such thing as the price elasticity of demand for cars. Moreover, the estimated price elasticity will depend o