Skip to main content

Food hygiene ratings and the full disclosure principle

In 2013 a system was introduced in Wales where restaurants and food outlets were required to display food hygiene ratings for all to see. This has seemingly led to an increase in food hygiene, prompting calls for the system to be extended across the UK. But is it necessary to force restaurants to display the rating? Textbook models of signalling would suggest not. Here's why:
          Restaurants are rated on a 6 point scale ranging from a cockroach infested 0 to very good 5. All restaurants have to be rated and so this is not at issue. The question is whether they should be forced to prominently display the rating. With that in mind, consider the incentives of restaurant owners:
        It is easiest to start with a restaurant that got a top, 5 rating. Clearly the owners have an incentive to display the high rating and show off how good the are. So they will likely display the rating whether forced to or not.  
        What about a restaurant with a 4 rating? You might think the owners would not want to display the rating as this will signal that they did not get a 5 rating. Suppose, however, the owners do not display the rating? The customer can reason that if the restaurant had got a 5 rating they would surely have displayed it. The lack of rating should, therefore, be interpreted as a signal the restaurant did not get a 5. And, who knows, it might have got a 0. It is, therefore, in the interests of the owners to display their 4 rating - it is not a 5 but it is better than a 3, or 0.
         What about a restaurant with a 3 rating? These owners would surely rather hide the fact they only got a 3. Again, however, we need to consider what the absence of a rating would signal. If all restaurants with a 5 or 4 display their ratings then the absence of a rating is a signal of 3 or below. And it is better to admit a 3 than have customers infer the rating might have been 2, or 0.
         This full-discloure principle extends to those with a 2 and 1 rating. The only restaurants that have no incentive to display their ratings are those with a 0. And we would hope that those are shut down anyway.
         Naturally, we might question whether reality would match the prediction of voluntary disclosure. But, I think there is a lot of anecdotal evidence to suggest it will. Indeed, the success or rating sites like TripAdvisor would seem to be dependent on it. Suppose, for instance, that only the best hotels, restaurants etc. wanted to be featured on rating websites. Then the website would have so few rankings as to be essentially useless. Things work because it is in the interests of all (or just about all) hotels and restaurants to let people know their rating. A rating of 7.5 out of 10, for example, is not great but better the customer know this than think the rating is 6.5 or worse.

Comments

Popular posts from this blog

Revealed preference, WARP, SARP and GARP

The basic idea behind revealed preference is incredibly simple: we try to infer something useful about a person's preferences by observing the choices they make. The topic, however, confuses many a student and academic alike, particularly when we get on to WARP, SARP and GARP. So, let us see if we can make some sense of it all.           In trying to explain revealed preference I want to draw on a  study  by James Andreoni and John Miller published in Econometrica . They look at people's willingness to share money with another person. Specifically subjects were given questions like:  Q1. Divide 60 tokens: Hold _____ at $1 each and Pass _____ at $1 each.  In this case there were 60 tokens to split and each token was worth $1. So, for example, if they held 40 tokens and passed 20 then they would get $40 and the other person $20. Consider another question: Q2. Divide 40 tokens: Hold _____ at $1 each and Pass ______ at $3 each. In this case each token given to th

Nash bargaining solution

Following the tragic death of John Nash in May I thought it would be good to explain some of his main contributions to game theory. Where better to start than the Nash bargaining solution. This is surely one of the most beautiful results in game theory and was completely unprecedented. All the more remarkable that Nash came up with the idea at the start of his graduate studies!          The Nash solution is a 'solution' to a two-person bargaining problem . To illustrate, suppose we have Adam and Beth bargaining over how to split some surplus. If they fail to reach agreement they get payoffs €a and €b respectively. The pair (a, b) is called the disagreement point . If they agree then they can achieve any pair of payoffs within some set F of feasible payoff points . I'll give some examples later. For the problem to be interesting we need there to be some point (A, B) in F such that A > a and B > b. In other words Adam and Beth should be able to gain from agreeing.

Some estimates of price elasticity of demand

In the  textbook on Microeconomics and Behaviour with Bob Frank we have some tables giving examples of price, income and cross-price elasticities of demand. Given that most of the references are from the 70's I'm working on an update for the forthcoming 3rd edition. So, here is a brief overview of where the numbers come from for the table on price elasticity of demand. Suggestions for other good sources much appreciated. Before we get into the numbers - the disclaimer. Price elasticities are tricky things to tie down. Suppose you want the price elasticity of demand for cars. This elasticity is likely to be different for rich or poor people, people living in the city or the countryside, people in France or Germany etc.etc. You then have to think if you want the elasticity for buying a car or using a car (which includes petrol, insurance and so on). So, there is no such thing as the price elasticity of demand for cars. Moreover, the estimated price elasticity will depend o