Skip to main content

Bolt, Leicester City and Brexit: confidence matters

Standard economic theory takes a very deterministic view of the world in that we solve for a unique equilibrium and expect that to describe what will happen. Game theory offers an alternative perspective in that most games have multiple equilibria and there is no reason to suppose that one of these equilibria is any more likely to describe what will happen than another. 
             For a long while the existence of multiple equilibria was seen as a 'problem'; surely the objective of economics was to say what would happen and not what might happen? Experimental economics, however, has shown that multiple equilibria are not so much a problem as a reflection on reality. When we observe two seemingly identical groups of people we often find they end up doing very different things. For instance, one group might end up cooperating and other not cooperating.
             Another way of looking at the multiple equilibrium problem is to say that small, hidden, seemingly irrelevant things can make a big difference. This view was popularized by Paul Omerod and his book Butterfly Economics. But, the idea that economic events can turn on a knife-edge still seems relatively ignored by a profession that prefers a more straightforward, deterministic view of the world. This is a shame because asking 'what if' questions can be interesting and informative. As a case in point consider the mysterious role of confidence.
            A few weeks ago Usain Bolt secured his position as the Greatest. Clearly Bolt is fit and strong. A crucial part in his success, though, is undoubtedly his ability to stay supremely relaxed under pressure. Indeed, a year ago, at the Athletics World Championships in Beijing, the Greatest tag looked under threat. Bolt stumbled through the semi-finals of the 100 metres and Justin Gatlin would surely win gold. Bolt, though, got it right when it mattered. Later, Bolt praised his coach for reminding him that he had nothing to fear. Confidence was the difference between winning and losing. How different things could have been?
           As a second example consider the remarkable success of Leicester City in winning the Premier League. Early in the season Leicester played Aston Villa. With 20 minutes to go Aston Villa were cruising, two goals to the good, and playing great football. Then, out of nowhere, Leicester scored three goals and won. This was surely a pivotal moment in the season. Leicester grew in confidence and became unstoppable while Villa fell into despair and hardly won another point for the rest of the season. If Villa had held on to win that game how different would things have been? Confidence can turn an ordinary team into world-beaters or no-hopers.
           And finally, let's look at Brexit. Before the referendum on Britain's membership of the EU, just about every economist in the land was predicting that Brexit will harm the UK economy. It surely will. For now, though, large parts of the economy still seem to be trundling along quite nicely. Which has given prominent Brexiters the chance to pour scorn on economists. The missing link is confidence. A majority of people voted for Brexit and so they, presumably, are happy and expecting great things. For the rest of us there is the realisation that we are still a long way from leaving the EU and so things might hold together for a while yet. The vote to leave the EU has not, therefore, caused a sudden and dramatic change of fortunes. Reality will have to kick in at some point but it is consumer and business confidence that will determine when. And there is no predicting when that might be.    
    

Comments

Popular posts from this blog

Revealed preference, WARP, SARP and GARP

The basic idea behind revealed preference is incredibly simple: we try to infer something useful about a person's preferences by observing the choices they make. The topic, however, confuses many a student and academic alike, particularly when we get on to WARP, SARP and GARP. So, let us see if we can make some sense of it all.           In trying to explain revealed preference I want to draw on a  study  by James Andreoni and John Miller published in Econometrica . They look at people's willingness to share money with another person. Specifically subjects were given questions like:  Q1. Divide 60 tokens: Hold _____ at $1 each and Pass _____ at $1 each.  In this case there were 60 tokens to split and each token was worth $1. So, for example, if they held 40 tokens and passed 20 then they would get $40 and the other person $20. Consider another question: Q2. Divide 40 tokens: Hold _____ at $1 each and Pass ______ at $3 each. In this case each token given to th

Nash bargaining solution

Following the tragic death of John Nash in May I thought it would be good to explain some of his main contributions to game theory. Where better to start than the Nash bargaining solution. This is surely one of the most beautiful results in game theory and was completely unprecedented. All the more remarkable that Nash came up with the idea at the start of his graduate studies!          The Nash solution is a 'solution' to a two-person bargaining problem . To illustrate, suppose we have Adam and Beth bargaining over how to split some surplus. If they fail to reach agreement they get payoffs €a and €b respectively. The pair (a, b) is called the disagreement point . If they agree then they can achieve any pair of payoffs within some set F of feasible payoff points . I'll give some examples later. For the problem to be interesting we need there to be some point (A, B) in F such that A > a and B > b. In other words Adam and Beth should be able to gain from agreeing.

Some estimates of price elasticity of demand

In the  textbook on Microeconomics and Behaviour with Bob Frank we have some tables giving examples of price, income and cross-price elasticities of demand. Given that most of the references are from the 70's I'm working on an update for the forthcoming 3rd edition. So, here is a brief overview of where the numbers come from for the table on price elasticity of demand. Suggestions for other good sources much appreciated. Before we get into the numbers - the disclaimer. Price elasticities are tricky things to tie down. Suppose you want the price elasticity of demand for cars. This elasticity is likely to be different for rich or poor people, people living in the city or the countryside, people in France or Germany etc.etc. You then have to think if you want the elasticity for buying a car or using a car (which includes petrol, insurance and so on). So, there is no such thing as the price elasticity of demand for cars. Moreover, the estimated price elasticity will depend o