Skip to main content

I am your leader - wherever you want to go I will follow

In economics there are two diametrically opposed ways of viewing politicians. For the most part we assume the benevolent social planner who acts to maximize social welfare. But, when it comes to specifically analysing political decision making we typically assume that politicians are just like everyone else - out to maximize their own payoff. If a politician's objectives coincide with those of society then we have no problem. But, there are, of course, lots of reasons to suppose that political and societal objectives do not coincide.
          A particularly important issue is that of electoral survival. Clearly, a politician needs to get elected in order to make a living. That means it is in a politicians interest to do things that go down well with the electorate. At first sight you might think that this aligns the incentives of the politician with those of society because the politician needs to do good things to get elected. There is, however, a problem of asymmetric information. In short, voters may not know what is good for them. This is not to say that voters a dumb. It is merely to reflect that voters have busy lives and cannot be expected to be informed about everything. That is why we have experts to advise and politicians to make informed decisions.
          So, what happens if a gap emerges between what voters want and what is good for them? We can hope for the benevolent social planner who does what is best. More realistically, however, we might have to accept that politicians are going to do what is popular. This, unfortunately, seems to explain why the United Kingdom is slipping ever further into disaster/farce territory. 
         The big issue in the UK is that of immigration. Just about every report or bit of research on the topic has shown that immigration is good for the UK. Immigrants create jobs, pay taxes, provide vital skills; international students work hard for a better future etc. etc. The popular perception, however, is that immigration is bad. Indeed, immigration seemingly has to take the blame for just about all of society's ills. We have, therefore, a worrying gap between reality and popular perception. In such circumstances, we might hope for politicians who do what is right and defend immigration. Unfortunately, though, the UK seems to be veering even more towards popularity politics. The Conservative Party Conference last week, for instance, appeared to have a strong anti-immigration vibe.
          In her conference speech, the Prime Minister, Theresa May, attacked the liberal elite who don't get Brexit. Surely, however, this is to miss the point. That 52 percent of voters wanted to leave the EU is a signal that something is wrong. But what? Given that immigration is good for this country then we surely we need to find the actual problem? The actual problem, I would suggest, has more to do with underfunding of public services and a basic miss-match between what people want and what they can realistically expect (given that money does not grow on trees). 'Tackling the immigration problem' is just going to make things worse. In particular, you do not tackle inequality with policies that will ultimately make the poor poorer.
         A more nuanced view of things is, however, very hard to sell to the electorate. Moreover, Theresa May's popularity seems sky high at the moment and so who can blame her for playing popularity politics. From an economic perspective she is doing exactly what we would expect her to - maximizing her own payoff. More important is how she can use this popularity. The comparison with Margaret Thatcher is particularly interesting. Margaret Thatcher was quite clever in mixing popular politics (reclaiming the Falklands) with unpopular but sensible policies (taking on the unions). This allowed her to square the circle of winning elections and good policy. Let's hope for something similar again.    
 

Comments

Popular posts from this blog

Revealed preference, WARP, SARP and GARP

The basic idea behind revealed preference is incredibly simple: we try to infer something useful about a person's preferences by observing the choices they make. The topic, however, confuses many a student and academic alike, particularly when we get on to WARP, SARP and GARP. So, let us see if we can make some sense of it all.           In trying to explain revealed preference I want to draw on a  study  by James Andreoni and John Miller published in Econometrica . They look at people's willingness to share money with another person. Specifically subjects were given questions like:  Q1. Divide 60 tokens: Hold _____ at $1 each and Pass _____ at $1 each.  In this case there were 60 tokens to split and each token was worth $1. So, for example, if they held 40 tokens and passed 20 then they would get $40 and the other person $20. Consider another question: Q2. Divide 40 tokens: Hold _____ at $1 each and Pass ______ at $3 each. In this case each token given to th

Nash bargaining solution

Following the tragic death of John Nash in May I thought it would be good to explain some of his main contributions to game theory. Where better to start than the Nash bargaining solution. This is surely one of the most beautiful results in game theory and was completely unprecedented. All the more remarkable that Nash came up with the idea at the start of his graduate studies!          The Nash solution is a 'solution' to a two-person bargaining problem . To illustrate, suppose we have Adam and Beth bargaining over how to split some surplus. If they fail to reach agreement they get payoffs €a and €b respectively. The pair (a, b) is called the disagreement point . If they agree then they can achieve any pair of payoffs within some set F of feasible payoff points . I'll give some examples later. For the problem to be interesting we need there to be some point (A, B) in F such that A > a and B > b. In other words Adam and Beth should be able to gain from agreeing.

Some estimates of price elasticity of demand

In the  textbook on Microeconomics and Behaviour with Bob Frank we have some tables giving examples of price, income and cross-price elasticities of demand. Given that most of the references are from the 70's I'm working on an update for the forthcoming 3rd edition. So, here is a brief overview of where the numbers come from for the table on price elasticity of demand. Suggestions for other good sources much appreciated. Before we get into the numbers - the disclaimer. Price elasticities are tricky things to tie down. Suppose you want the price elasticity of demand for cars. This elasticity is likely to be different for rich or poor people, people living in the city or the countryside, people in France or Germany etc.etc. You then have to think if you want the elasticity for buying a car or using a car (which includes petrol, insurance and so on). So, there is no such thing as the price elasticity of demand for cars. Moreover, the estimated price elasticity will depend o