Skip to main content

Pensions and present day bias

In the UK budget a week or so ago the Chancellor surprised most by announcing a radical shake up of the UK pension system. According to the old system retirees, with a private pension plan, were essentially forced to buy an annuity that would smooth income over their remaining life. Under the new system retirees can withdraw the money and spend it as they wish. So, if they want to splash out on a Lamborghini sports car then fine (according to the pensions minister). 
           What has interested me most about the pension changes is the public reaction. Immediately, people began questioning whether it made sense to let retirees have freedom of choice. Are pensioners capable of make informed rational decisions about how to spend their savings? Will they not blow it all and be left to live out their lives on state support? To most people it seemed obvious that some might make dumb, inappropriate choices. And, for me, this illustrates how divorced from reality economic theory has become.
          Thankfully, we now have a theory of why people may make inconsistent choices over time (see, for example, the article 'Doing it now or later' by Ted O'Donoghue and Matthew Rabin). The theory points towards time-inconsistent preferences with a present day bias. The bias basically means we treat today as 'special' relative to the future. And that means we may be unable to stick to long term plans. For instance, on Friday you might plan to clean the garage on Saturday, on Saturday you think 'maybe next week', and on Monday you regret not cleaning the garage. The present bias in this example manifest's itself on Saturday: From the perspective of Friday or Monday, Saturday is just any other day. But, when Saturday is today it's special, and you do not want to clean the garage!
          Everybody is surely familiar with the consequences of time-inconsistency - planning to do something, but then not wanting to do it when the time comes. The idea that pensioners might blow all their pension money unwisely seemed common sense to most. Standard economic models, however, take no account at all of time-inconsistency. And even though we now have simple models of time-inconsistent preferences it is very rare to see them applied. A fundamental part of human behavior is, therefore, completely neglected by standard economic theory! That's weird, and frankly, makes economics look silly.
         This divorce between reality and theory is a consequence of economists becoming trapped in a world where people are assumed rational, even though we know people are systematically biased in many ways. To date, behavioral economics has done nothing more than chip away at the edges of this monolith. Hopefully, things will change in the future.
       But, what of the liberalization of the pension rules? Some argue that because of time-inconsistent preferences the changes will be harmful. And, no doubt there will be some who blow their pension money in a way they subsequently regret. The old system, however, forced everyone to buy an annuity despite their being many for whom this was not the best option. Trading off the interests of some against others is always difficult. But, I think the old system was clearly weighted too much on the side of those likely to blow the money. Many were having to choose bad options for the benefit of a few who could not be trusted to spend the money wisely.
          Present bias does exist, however. And so it is still important to try and nudge pensioners to spend their money wisely. Note, though, a fundamental characteristic of a good nudge - it should not limit the options available. The pension reforms announced by the government fit this model - they liberalize choice while still nudging pensioners in the direction that will be sensible for most.

Comments

Popular posts from this blog

Revealed preference, WARP, SARP and GARP

The basic idea behind revealed preference is incredibly simple: we try to infer something useful about a person's preferences by observing the choices they make. The topic, however, confuses many a student and academic alike, particularly when we get on to WARP, SARP and GARP. So, let us see if we can make some sense of it all.           In trying to explain revealed preference I want to draw on a  study  by James Andreoni and John Miller published in Econometrica . They look at people's willingness to share money with another person. Specifically subjects were given questions like:  Q1. Divide 60 tokens: Hold _____ at $1 each and Pass _____ at $1 each.  In this case there were 60 tokens to split and each token was worth $1. So, for example, if they held 40 tokens and passed 20 then they would get $40 and the other person $20. Consider another question: Q2. Divide 40 tokens: Hold _____ at $1 each and Pass ______ at $3 each. In this case each token given to th

Nash bargaining solution

Following the tragic death of John Nash in May I thought it would be good to explain some of his main contributions to game theory. Where better to start than the Nash bargaining solution. This is surely one of the most beautiful results in game theory and was completely unprecedented. All the more remarkable that Nash came up with the idea at the start of his graduate studies!          The Nash solution is a 'solution' to a two-person bargaining problem . To illustrate, suppose we have Adam and Beth bargaining over how to split some surplus. If they fail to reach agreement they get payoffs €a and €b respectively. The pair (a, b) is called the disagreement point . If they agree then they can achieve any pair of payoffs within some set F of feasible payoff points . I'll give some examples later. For the problem to be interesting we need there to be some point (A, B) in F such that A > a and B > b. In other words Adam and Beth should be able to gain from agreeing.

Some estimates of price elasticity of demand

In the  textbook on Microeconomics and Behaviour with Bob Frank we have some tables giving examples of price, income and cross-price elasticities of demand. Given that most of the references are from the 70's I'm working on an update for the forthcoming 3rd edition. So, here is a brief overview of where the numbers come from for the table on price elasticity of demand. Suggestions for other good sources much appreciated. Before we get into the numbers - the disclaimer. Price elasticities are tricky things to tie down. Suppose you want the price elasticity of demand for cars. This elasticity is likely to be different for rich or poor people, people living in the city or the countryside, people in France or Germany etc.etc. You then have to think if you want the elasticity for buying a car or using a car (which includes petrol, insurance and so on). So, there is no such thing as the price elasticity of demand for cars. Moreover, the estimated price elasticity will depend o